Investment Behaviour in the Laboratory

  • Diego Pulido Marine de Montaignact
  • Jim Engle-Warnic
futuristic image of written formulas

Abstract

This is a Preliminary Working Paper for GRI.

This paper is an experimental study of dynamic investment decisions. The  goal  of  the  experiment  is  to  test  theoretical  predictions of the effect of human capital on investment. Subjects make repeated portfolio allocation decisions, allocating their money between cash and a gamble that represents the market.  Human  capital  is simulated  by the degree to which income is correlated with the market. This preliminary  paper  describes the model  and the experimental design.

Introduction and justification

 The economic well-being of individuals depends significantly on their invest­ment decisions. Through their life, individuals must choose the portfolio of assets for their savings. This portfolio can include cash, real assets (real es­ tate), and financial assets and instruments such as bonds, stocks or options. Some portfolios have higher expected returns, but normally this comes at a cost of a higher risk of losses. The main decision investors have to make is the level of risk they are willing to assume. This is not a one time decision. Normally, investors have the ability to adjust their portfolio along their life cycle.

The dynamic portfolio decision has been studied by economists for decades. The seminal work of Samuelson (1963, 1969) predicts that an investor’s port­ folio choice will be independent from her time-horizon. The chosen portfolio will depend mainly on the investor’s attitude towards risk. Nonetheless, this prediction arises under  a very restrictive set assumptions.  One them is that  the investor has no income. An individual’s future income could be sum­ marized by her human capital, which can be defined as the present value of  the expected  future income she expects to earn through  her  life-time:

T

Human  Capitalt  = Et[  L /38 Income 8 ]

s=t+l

(1)

Human capital acts as a form of wealth that can be added to a person’s other assets in order to calculate her total wealth. By including human cap­ ital, the portfolio decision begins to depend on the time horizon. The main result is that, under a very general set of circumstances, human capital will act as an implicit investment on the riskless asset. This will lead investors to place a smaller share of their current savings in safe assets in order to reach their target level of portfolio risk. When making the investment  decision what matters is not the current level of savings, but total wealth: human capital plus current asset holdings. By including human capital, the invest­ ment path will depend on 1) the amount of human capital relative to current period savings, 2) hte uncertainty of human capital, and 3) the degree to which  human  capital is correlated  with the returns of other  assets.

Many studies have attempted to  contrast  the  theoretical  results  with the  data.  Nonetheless,  these  analysis  are difficult  given the characteristics of the available data. For instance, it is difficulte to measure human capital because future income is unknown. This is difficult for both investors and researchers. Also, it is difficult to asses a person’s attitudes towards risk, or how it evolves over time. Additionally, when looking at data one should take into account that it is whole households, instead of individuals who usually make investment decisions. Finally, one could expect that preferences will not remain unchanged at different stages of life.  Instead,  one can expect  that they will evolve due to factors such as career histories or by the con­ ditions currently experienced  by the economy.  Additionally,  as  Roussanov

{2010) mentions, given the quality of the information  available,  the study  of portfolio choices suffer from identification problems, mainly because it is difficult to disentangle in panel data the cohort effects on investment from the  age effects.1

Experimental economics is a tool that can overcome the limitations of other empirical approaches. The advantage of an experiment is that it al­  lows us to study investment  decisions  in a controlled  setting.  This allow  us to control the main variables and parameters relevant to the investment decision. It also allow us to measure the participants’ attitudes toward risk and to have an accurate measure  of their  human   capital.

This document describes an experiment whose aim is to stud how in­ vestors make dynamic investment decisions. Specifically, our interest in centered on the effect  of  human  capital on these decisions.  This proposal  is organized as follows. Section 1 highlights the most important theoretical results related with the  proposed  experiment.  2  summarizes  the  empiri­ cal studies related with human capital and portfolio choices. This includes studies using survey data and experimental results. Section 4 describes the theoretical model that will be used  as reference for the experiment.  Section  5 describes  the experimental task.

 

1. Dynamic portfolio and human capital theory lit­erature review 

The seminal works of Mossin (1968), Samuelson (1969) and Merton (1969) lay the foundations  of the theory  of investment  over the life cycle.     These 1This issue is explained in detail by Ameriks and Zeldes (2004) and Guiso and Sodini (2013) models make two important predictions. The first is that, at any age, it is optimal to invest in risky assets. The second is that the share of an indi­ vidual’s wealth invested in risky assets should remain constant independent of the investment  horizon. 2  This prediction  is not  in line with the habit­  ual recommendation given by financial advisors: invest more in risky assets when one is young and less as one gets closer to retirement. Nonetheless, these models make a series of assumptions that limit their ability to explain actual investment  behaviour.  The most  important  are the following:

  1. There is no labor
  2. Asset returns  are identical  and  independently distributed.
  3. Preferences are additively separable over
  4. Markets are frictionless (no transaction
  5. There are no additional sources of income and all assets are

Merton (1971) extends the basic model by adding riskless and tradeable labor income. He shows that income leads people  to invest  more  in the risky assets when young. The intuition of this result is that having labor income is equivalent to an implicit investment in a riskless asset. Individuals take this fact into account when making their investment decisions. As described in equation 1, future income can be summarized by human capital. When young, individuals have a large amount of human capital and few financial assets. Thus if they wish to invest a certain portion of their wealth (human capital plus  financial  assets)  in  a portfolio  with  a certain  degree of risk, they will have to invest a relatively large portion of their financial wealth in the risky asset. As individuals get older, their financial assets grow and their human capital shrinks. As this  happens,  to keep  their  desired  level of investment, they have to reduce the portion that they invest in the financial asset. The result is that, as individuals age, their share of the risky investment falls. This result is robust to the relaxation of other assumptions  of the baseline model.

In general, human capital is neither easily tradeable over time nor risk­ less.  Bodie et al. (1992)  incorporate     non-tradable  flexible labor supply in their model. They also make human capital uncertain, but they keep it in­ dependent from the movements in the returns of the financial assets. They show that, under these assumption, it is still optimal to hold a safer portfolio the closer the investor is to retirement. They also show that having labor flexibility increases risk-taking. Heaton and Lucas (1997) develop a similar model, but allow for stochastic income that is uncorrelated with the risky asset. They find that, as long as income is not highly correlated with the  price of the risky asset, it will act as an implicit holding  of the safe asset. This gives an incentive for the agents to hold a larger share of the risky  asset.  They find, for a wide range of parameters,  that the optimal response  is to invest all savings in stocks. In a similar way, Koo (1999) develops a model with uninsurable random income and liquidity constraints. He shows that these two conditions will lead the investor to invest less in the risky asset.

Viceira (2001) also presents a model with labor risk. He shows that employed investors will allocate more resources to the risky asset than un­ employed ones. He also shows that as the idiosyncratic risk of human capital increases, the willingness to hold the risky asset drops. This drop increases even more if income is positively correlated with the risky asset. The opti­ mal portfolio allocation for stocks is larger the longer the retirement horizon of the investor. They also show that a positive correlation between labor income and the market return further reduces the desired investment in the risky asset.

The models from Heaton and Lucas (1997), Koo (1999) and Viceira (2001) assume an infinite horizon. This feature makes these models of lim­ ited use to understand issues related with the life-cycle. Cocco  (2005) build a finite-horizon model with uninsurable labor income risk. They find that despite this risk, labor income (uncorrelated  with equity risk) is perceived as a better substitute for riskless bonds than equities. This leads to higher demand for equities, especially when individuals are young. Interestingly, they found that including a small probability of a very bad labor income lowers the allocation to equities, bringing it closer to empirical observations.

Benzoni et al. (2007) find contrasting results by assuming cointegration between the labor income and the market returns. They propose a model in which labor income is cointegrated with the dividend process of the market portfolio. In contrast with earlier results, these paper finds that  it  is opti­  mal for young investors to hold short positions in the risky portfolio. The intuition  behind  this  result  is related  to the  fact  that  when  human capital is cointegrated with the risky asset it has stock-like characteristics. Young investors that have a large stock of human capital are very exposed to the market risk and will limit the additional risk that they will take by investing directly on risky  assets.

In a similar manner as Bodie et al.  (1992),  Gomes et al.  (2008)  stud­  ies a model with variable labor supply, but assumes uncertain wages. He finds that variable labor supply raises the level of optimal equity holdings. Endogenizing the labor supply allows us to look at the insurance like charac­ teristics of labor: people can work more to make up for losses in the financial market.  Fagereng et al. (2013) builds on the model of Gomes et al. (2008)  by adding a small probability of a large loss and a participation cost. These changes make the model fit better two empirical observations: the low level of participation in the stock market and the large share of investors leaving the risky  asset  market  when they reach retirement.

Peijnenburg (2014) presents a model with ambiguity averse investors and uncertainty about the equity premium. With his model he is able to explain two empirical observations: the low percentage of the portfolio invested in equities  and the low participation  in the stock  market.

 

2. Empirical literature on dynamic portfolio choice theory

Heaton and Lucas (2000) argue that households with more business income will invest less in stocks given the higher level of background income that they face.

Ameriks and Zeldes (2004) uses panel data from TIAA-CREF contribu­ tors, and find that the participation in the stock market has a hump-shape during the life cycle and that the composition of the portfolio shows little change. Fagereng et al. (2013) make a similar study, but with households instead of individuals. They use information about the life-cycle portfolio allocation on a sample of 164,000 households in Norway, using 15 years of  tax registry information. They have the advantage of being able to see the entire portfolio (instead of only retirement savings as Ameriks and Zeldes (2004)) They find that share of risky assets in the household portfolio be­  gins to diminish in middle life, as retirement approaches. They also find limited  participation  at  all ages,  and  a tendency  to exit  the  market before retirement.

The level of sophistication of the participants in the market is related  with their willingness to take risk. Using survey information for Norway, Calvet et al. (2007) find that more sophisticated and educated households take more risk, but also are more efficient  investing.

Cardak and Wilkins (2009) studies the determinants of household port­ folio decision looking at data from the Households, Incomes and Labour Dynamics in Australia survey. They find that risky asset holdings are nega­ tively related with poor health and labor income uncertainty. Additionally, they find that risky asset holdings seem to be positively related with financial awareness and knowledge. Angerer and Lam (2009) uses information from the US National Longitudinal Survey of Youth and finds that permanent incomes risk reduces the level of investment in stocks, while temporary risk does not. An important factor that is taken into account is as estimation of human wealth.

Jin (2011) shows that by including housing and private business in the portfolio of risky assets of households the empirical evidence matches the theoretical prediction (Merton (1971), Bodie et al. (1992), Heaton and Lucas (1997)) that  the share ofrisky  assets in the portfolio  of younger  households   in higher. Veld-Merkoulova (2011) studies the importance of age and self­ reported planning horizon in portfolio investment. She finds that  longer  planning horizons are positively related with investments in risky financial assets.

Yilmazer and Lich (2013) approach the problem of how portfolio deci­ sions are taken in a household with several people with different risk prefer­ ences. Using information from the health and retirement study, they show that the risky share in the portfolio increases depending on the risk prefer­ ences of the spouse who has more bargaining  power.

Calvet and Sodini (2014) is able to overcome many of the identification problems by using portfolio information from a panel of 23,000 twins. They find evidence that both participation in risky financial asset markets and the risky share conditional on participation are positively correlated with wealth. Using twins also allows them to control for time, cohort and age effects. Their evidence provides evidence that expected human capital postively drives the risky share of investment  portfolios.

 

3. Related  experimental literature

 To the best of our knowledge, no one has used experiments to study the importance of human capital on dynamic  investment  decisions  in  a way that is similar to the way we describe in this proposal. Nonetheless, several studies have use experiments to study how the length of the investment horizon affects the portfolio decisions.

Klos (2004) studies the importance of the time horizon in the dynamic portfolio decisions. He compares two treatments: one in which the partic­ ipants made a single investment decision and one where they made a two period sequence in investment choices. Fifty-one business students took part in the study. All the participants participated in both treatments, but their order was randomized. They did not find a statistically significant difference in the average investment made in the one period treatment and in the first period of the two periods treatment. This is consistent with the empirical models.

Sundali and Guerrero (2009) studied an experiment in which subjects make repeated asset allocations to stocks, bonds and cash. The novel ingre­ dient of the experiment is that in one of their treatments they gave the in­ vestors projections about the expected future value of their portfolio. Those participants that received  projections  allocate a larger share of their wealth to stocks. Their experimental task had 20 periods. The subjects were given  an endowment in the first period that they had to reallocate, each period, between a risky and riskless assets. The expected returns on the stock came from the  historical  distribution.  60 subjects took  part  in the experiment.

Brocas et al. (2014) use a dynamic portfolio choice experiment to asses people’s risk attitudes. They find a high heterogeneity of preferences among the subjects. Nonetheless, they find that decreasing absolute risk aversion  and increasing relative risk aversion are the most prevalent risk types. Their experiment use a dynamic investment task with two assets (one safe and one risky) and 10 investment periods. Each player goes through 15 investment paths (one is randomly chosen for compensation) for a total of 150 deci­ sions. Additionally, the players  go through  5 practice  paths.  All  players are subject to the same market  draws.  A  total  of  120  subjects  participate in the experiment.  The return  of  the  safe asset  is 3% and the  return  of  the risky asset is 6% with and standard deviation  of  55%.  The parameters do not  change through  the experiment.  They do not  allow borrowing   and short sales, because either could lead to taking money from the participants (participants ending the task with a negative balance).

Carbone and Infante (2014) Studies the saving and consumption deci­ sions in a dynamic setting under three scenarios: certainty, risk and ambigu­ ity. The saving-consumption choice is not directly relevant for our project. Nonetheless, the experimental design is interesting for our experiment. Each participant  only follow one treatment.

Kapteyn and Teppa {2014) measures risk preferences and then used them in a portfolio models that explains portfolio shares and accounts for incom­ plete portfolios and fixed costs. The risk free asset has  a 3% return.  The risky asset is a binary lottery that can either increase 20% or decrease 10% with equal probability.

 

4. Theoretical model

 4.1  MODEL DESCRIPTION

 This section describes the theoretical version of our experimental treatment. The treatment is a simplified version of the more general versions of the dynamic portfolio choice problem that are described in the literature. The version of the model described here follows closely the experimental task that we plan to apply in the lab, and most importantly, arrives to the same conclusions as the more general versions of the  model.

The economy in the model lasts periods. in = 0, the agent  receives  an initial endowment of Wo. The decision made by the investor in every period from = 1, …T is how to split the available wealth between a risky asset St and cash (Bt):                                                    (2)

The amount invested in cash will gain no interest and will pass to the  next period, free of risk. On the other hand, the amount invested in the risky asset will receive a return equal to r8 • The price of the risky asset evolves according to: (3)

The return on the risky asset is uncertain. Each period, the risky asset return can  have  a negative  or  a positive  return:  rd  or  ru.  The probabil­ ity of having a negative or positive return, in a given period, is fixed and independent  across periods: (4)

The probability  of a high market  is,

(5)

 

Additionally, in each period the agent receives an income (Yt), which could either take a low (yl ) or high (yh) value. Each value can occur with probability pl and ph = 1 – pl , respectively. The probability of having a high or a low income is correlated with the risky market outcome for that period, so that,

 

The correlation between income and risky asset processes stays the same across periods  so that, Pi pl , E {1, …T}.                                       (7)

Following the definition of Deaton, the cash in hand available to the subject to invest  and save is and

Wo So + Bo                                             (8)

Wt = Yt-1 + (1 + rf_ 1)Bt-1 + Bt-1 for t E {1, …T}.                (9)

 

The preferences of the subject are described by a constant relative risk aversion (CRRA) utility function

(W)l-7

u(W ) = {

ln(W)

(10)

As its  name  implies,  this  function  has  the  property  that  the  level  of risk aversion of  the  subject  is  independent  from  his  level  of  wealth.  His risk preferences  are summarized  by  ‘Y.  A  higher  ‘Y  means  a higher  degree of risk aversion. If ‘Y is zero, the agent is risk neutral.  If  ‘Y  is negative the  agent is risk preferring. We could have instead assumed a function with decreasing  relative  risk  aversion.  Nonetheless,  Wachter  and  Yogo  (2010) and Chiappori and  Paiella  (2011)  show  that  there  is  strong  evidence  that  the investor preferences are better represented by a constant relative  risk aversion  utility  function.

We abstract from the consumption decision in the model so that we can isolate the investment decision. The objective of the investor will be to maximize the expected utility of his wealth in period T: The optimization problem can be summarized as follows max      E{ 6T (Wr )1-‘Y }

t=T -1                           1-‘V

t ,  t t=O                                                I

(11)

subject to

Wo So Bo                                          

(12)

Wt Yt-1 + (1 + r%_ 1)St-l + Bt-1 for, E {1, …T}.

(13)

The agent  also faces a liquidity  constraint

(14)

 

In any period,  the agent  cannot  invest more than  his cash in  hand.

A second restriction is that the agent can only invest positive quantities  in the risky asset. This is the same as saying that he can not short sell the risky asset  (15)

If we take  into account  these restrictions  and the fact  that  the agent can decide every period how to invest, our problem at any E 0, …T – 1 boils down to maximizing the expected utility of wealth in + 1. We can

make this simplification because the market return process is independent across periods and the income process is only contemporaneously correlated with the risky asset. This means that the decisions, market conditions, and income  experienced  up  to  don’t  have  any  repercussions  on the  market, income or wealth accumulation beyond  + 1.

Additionally, we will assume that = 1. This means that the agent doesn’t experience impatience across periods. The reason for this assump­ tion is that the lab treatment  will not  mimic in anyway the time dimension  of the subject decision. The reason is that all the stages of the game will take place withing the same experimental session. The only distinctive moments for the participants are when the experiment begins and when it ends. They never get the chance to show their time preferences, because they receive only a single payment.

Nonetheless, we should  take  into account  that  even though  the  agent is constrained to invest at most his cash in hand in every period, he will consider in his decision all his wealth (cash in hand and expected future income). We will denominate the sum of his future income as his human capital

HCt  Et{  Yi}. i=t+l

(16)

One important item to specify is how the agent will include his human capital in his period investment decision. Because his human capital is uncertain, he cannot simply add up the value of his human capital.  If we  take into account the uncertainty associated with his human  capital  the agent will value his future human capital differently depending on his risk preferences. His future stream of income could end up taking many different accumulated values up to T. For the subject his future stream of income is like participating in a lottery that could take different values with different probabilities.  Because we assume that the period income will take only   two values ( yh or yl ) with fixed probabilities (ph and pl ), the stream  of  future income can be modeled with a Bernoulli process {Yi} for i E  { t + 1, …T},  such  that:

Yt i.i.d  “‘ Ph  = 1-pl  E  [O, 1].

(17)

The space of elementary events of {Yi} will be given by

n = , were w takes the formw ( yh, yl , yl , …).

(18)

The number of elements in n is given by 2(T-t) . Nonetheless, we can simplify it by grouping the the elements of n giving the same accumulated

income. In that case, we end up with only – distinctive values for the future income. if N h denotes the number of times that the income will be high in the future, we can find the probability of having N h high incomes (and – – N h low incomes) as:

With this probability we can calculate the expected value of the future human capital

The expression in the last set of brackets in the right hand side gives us each of the possible values of the accumulated income. The rest of the expression in the right hand side gives us the probability of getting high and T – low incomes in T – trials.

Equation 20 shows the expected value of  future  income.  Nonetheless, unless the agent is risk neutral, he will associate a lower value to his future income.   To  find  the  present  value  of  the  future  uncertain  income,  we  can observe that it is equivalent to participating in a lottery that will pay (jyh +(T – – j )y 1with probability P[Nh = n]. So, if we want to know the future value of this lottery, we have to find its certainty  equivalent  (CE): the certain amount for which the agent would be willing to trade his lottery. For this to be the case, this certain  amount  should  give  the  subject  at  least as much  utility  as the  one  he  gets  from keeping  it.  It  is important to keet the current cash in hand position of the agent when calculating the certainty equivalent. The reason is that we are comparing the following two situation:s the certainty equivalent plus his cash in hand in hand and his future uncertain income plus his cash in hand. Taking this into account we have that

One last item to take into account is the correlation between the next period risky asset return and labor income. This correlation is taken into account by the agent when making his investment decision. In the next period, the investor will face four possible situations: 1) ru and yh, 2) ru and 1,  3) rd and yh, and 4)  hd  and 1.

The labor income beyond + 1 only enters the investment decision for the next period through the certainty equivalent for = 1, as described by equation 21. The reason is because income from t+2 onwards is independent from period’s  market  and from periods  and + 1 incomes.

Given the conditions described above, we can rewrite the optimization problem of the investor as follows:

 

max

E{ (Wt+l + CEt+1)1-7 }£or = 0, …T

(22)

( St ,Bt )                       1- “( subject to % =    +   (Wt Yt-1 + (1 + rf_ 1)St-l + Bt-1 for, E {1, …T}                 (24)

St Bt :S Wt                                           (25)

 

(26)

There are some interesting things to notice about this new representation of the optimization  problem.  First, the future stream of income,  from + 2 onwards, can be summarized by the certainty equivalent. Given the liquidity constraint  that  does not  allow the  agent  to take  loans,  the human   capital beyond  + 2 acts as a cash position  equivalent  to the certainty  equivalent.

The agent may like to invest a certain fraction of his total wealth (cash in hand plus the certainty equivalen of the human capital) in the risky  asset,  but is constraint to invest at most Wt. on the other hand, next period income Yt+l is different from the income of the other periods because is correlated with the market return for which the subject has to make a decision in the current period. This income will have an effect in the decision of the agent depending on the kind  of correlation that  it has with the market.

 

4.2  OPTIMAL STRATEGY

 This model has to be solved numerically. The optimal strategy of the subject depends on the specific path that the income and market return processes take. The main difference between different realizations of the income and returns processes is that they leave the investor with different quantities of cash in hand. Keeping other things equal, subjects who experience relatively unlucky paths (low market returns or income) will have a lower cash in  hand, which will affect their level of total wealth. On the other hand, the expectations about the future  are  path  independent.  This  is  so,  because our model (and the analogous lab experiment) assumes that there is no correlation  across periods  for the income or the risky asset  returns.

The main results from the model are the   following:

  1. More risk averse investors (those with higher 1) will invest an smaller share of their cash in hand  in the risky
  1. The higher the volatility of the risky asset ( higher np( -p)) the lower the investor investment  in the risky
  2. Investors with larger human capital will invest a larger share of their cash in hand in the risky asset. A corollary from this result is that, other things equal, people with longer time horizons will tend to invest more in the risky
  3. The higher the volatility of the labor income the lower the investment in the risky
  4. If the correlation between the labor income and the market return is positive, the investor will invest less in the risky asset, compared with the situation where there is no correlation. The intuition is that labor income equates partially to an implicit  investment  in the risky
  5. If the correlation between the labor income and the market return is negative, the investor will invest more in the risky asset, compared with the situation where there in no correlation. The intuition is that with negative correlation labor income partially hedges  the  market risk.

The theoretical predictions enumerated above are the ones that we want to test in the lab. The explicit solution to the model depends on the as­ sumption made about the parameters of the model. In section 5, were we describe the  set of specific treatments  that  we  plan  to follow  in the lab,  we will describe the expected optimal path of investment under different circumstances.

We want to simulate the following  scenarios,

  • no labor income;
  • fixed labor income;
  • risky income whose movement is independent from the financial mar­ ket
  • risky income that is positively correlated with the financial market and;
  • risky income that is negatively  correlated  with the financial

 

5. Experimental task

 The experimetal task follows the theoretical model described above. It will have the following phases:

  1. First the subject learns about the rules of the task.  Then they receive   a complete description of the particular circumstances that they will face.  They will be informed about
    • The number of periods  of the task:  T;
    • Their initial endowment: Wo;
    • The values that the risky  asset  could  take:  ru  or rd  ;
    • The odds of getting and ru  or rd  return:  pu  or pd  ;
    • The possible values that  their  income could take:  yh  or   1;
    • The odds of getting a yh or return given the risky asset asset outcome: P [Yt 1 l rt ru] , P [Yt 1 l rt rd ] , P [Yt Yh l rt ru] and P [Yt yh l rt  ru].   Pedagogically,  this  is the most difficult piece of information to give to the participants. To make the probabilities easy to understand for the participants we will de­ pict them with lottery wheels. First, we will represent the risky market two possible returns with a wheel. This wheel will spin first, deciding the outcome for the risky asset return. Once this outcome is known we will move to the income market that will be represented by to wheels. Each will operate depending on the risky asset return outcome. This means that each will for the income process is depicting the conditional probability of getting and low of high outcome conditional on the risky return outcome.
  1. Next, the subjects are asked to split their endowment between the  risky asset and cash. After making this choice, the economy moves to the end of the current period  (beginning of the following   period).
  2. After making the decision, the risky asset  return  for the next  period is
  3. Then, given the risky asset outcome the correct wheel  is chosen for the income the period  outcome is
  4. Given these two outcomes and the investment decision taken by the subject, the new cash in hand is
  5. After knowing about his new cash in hand, the agent has to make a new investment
  6. The same processes is repeated  T
  7. At the end of the treatment, the participant will be informed of her  final period accumulated

When making their choices, the subjects face the restrictions  faced  in  the theoretical  description of the task.  Namely:

  • Their investment should be equal or lower to their current cash in
  • They cannot invest a negative quantity on the risky asset. This is, that they can not take short position on the risky

The treatment described above will be repeated under  different  assump­ tions about the parameters. A treatment can be characterized by T, Wo, rU, rd , Pu , Pd , yh, Y 1, P [Yt  1 l  rt  ru], P [Yt  1 l  rt rd ]   , P [Yt  Yh l   rt ru]

and P [Yt yh l rt ru].

 

 5.1   TREATMENTS

 This section describes the parametrization of the different  treatments  that  we plan to apply in the lab. In an ideal setting, we would practice the treatments with dozens of risky asset conditions. Nonetheless,  given  the time limitations, we will analyze two versions of each of the treatments described: one with high volatility and high risky asset returns and one with low volatility and low returns. The reason why this is useful is that these scenarios should allow us to get interesting responses from agents across wide levels of risk aversion.

The two risky  asset settings that we plan to consider  are the  following

  • Low volatility:  pu  = 5, pd   = 0.5,  ru  = 0.35,  and  rd  = -0.25
  • High volatility:  pu  = 5, pd  = 0.5, ru = 0.7,  and rd  = -0.35.

As we will see in the description of the different treatments, other things equal, we would expect that agents with low risk aversion (‘Y = 0.2, for example) will often invest close to 100% of the cash in hand in the low volatility  treatments.   On  the  other  hand,  agents  with  high  risk aversion (.X = 2, for example) will tend to invest close to 0% in the high volatility treatment. We will see this more clearly in the description of each of the treatment  scenarios.

Each treatment will last = 6 periods. This number of periods is conve­ nient because it is long enough to allow us to make meaningful comparisons and short enough to be able to limit the possible values of the accumulated return. Additionally, making each treatment shorter allow to play more treatments, before the time is up or the participants may have exhausted  their concentration to solve questions. With  6 periods,  the main  test  that  we will perform is to compare the behavior in the first three and the  last three periods.

After completing all the treatments, one of them will be chosen at ran­ dom to make the payment to the participants.

 

  • No income treatment

 The defining characteristics of this treatment is that there  is no  income.  The participants only receive the initial endowment,  Wo.  The parameters for this treatment  are the following:

= 6,  Wo = 10, pu  = 0.5, pd  =  0.5

yh = 0, yl  = 0,

  • P[Yt 1 l rt  ru] , P [Yt  1l rt  = rd]:  N/A  (no income)
  • P[Yt Yh l rt  ru] , P [Yt  yh l rt  = rd]:  N/ A  (no income)

One important adjustment made to this treatment is that the initial endowment is larger compared with the treatments that have period income. We make this to make the expected payoff from this treatment  comparable  to the expected payoff  of the treatments with income where  Wo =  10

The optimal strategy predicted by our theoretical model is described in the following figure.

As the figure shows the percentage that the person is predicted to invest in this  scenario is the  same independent  of  the  level  of  income. The only thing that makes a difference in the choice is how volatile is the is the risky market  return  and how risk  averse is the subject.

 

Investment  (optimal Strategy)

nolncome

 Investment  (optimal Strategy)

nolncome

 .8

.6

.4

.2

Period                                                                                                                 Period

—-e—-  gamma 0.2       —+— gamma 0.5

—-. gamma 2      — gamma 4

         .        gamma 0.8

—-e—- gamma 0.2    —+— gamma 0.5   —A– gamma 0.8

— gamma 2         — gamma 4

 

  • Fixed income treatment

 The defining characteristics of this treatment is that period income  Yt  is fixed and known with certainty. We choose the period income so that it will be equal to the expected  value of the income in the risky  treatments  that  are described below.  The parameters  for this treatment  are the  following

= 6, Wo = 10, pu  = 0.5, pd  =  0.5

yh  yl  = 2,

P[Y 11rt ru], P [Yt rt = rd]: N/A (fixed income)

P[Yt  yh l rt ru], P [Yt yh l rt = rd]:  N/A (fixed income) .

Having income has the effect of making agents want to invest a larger part of their cash in hand in the beginning and  a smaller  one  at  the end. This has a simple intuition. What happens is that each period the subject wants to invest a fraction of his wealth in the risky asset .  The problem  is that his wealth is not only composed of his cash at hand but also by his human capital. Because in the initial periods his cash in hand in relatively  low to his total wealth , he will invest a relatively large portion of this cash  in hand in the risky period . He could even want  to invest more than  100% of his cash in hand, but is constrained by the fact that he does not  have access to credit.  As the periods progress a smaller portion of his wealth is in human capital and the portion that he want to invest in the risky  asset will  be available as cash in hand, making the percentage  investment   smaller.

 

  • Risky income uncorrelated with the risky  asset

 The defining characteristic of this treatment  is  that  the  period  income  is  risky. Each period, the income will take a high(yh) or low ( yz ) value with probabilities ph  and pl   = 1-ph , respectively.  Nontheless,  the income prob­abilities are independent from the risky  asset  returns.  For  this treatment  the parameters  are the following

T  = 6,  Wo = 10, pu  = 0.5, pd  = 0.5

yh = 4, yl  = 0,

  • P[Yt Y z l rt  ru]  = 5, P [Yt  Yz l rt  = rd ]  = 0.5
  • P[Yt Yh l rt  ru]  = 5, P [Yt  Yhl rt  rd ]  = 0.5.

The values of yh and yl were chosen so that Et[Yt+l ] = 2. This  is the income  used  in  the  fixed  income treatment.

When we compare this treatment with the one with fixed income, we can see that the main difference is each period the agent is willing to invest a slightly larger portion of his cash in hand in the risky income. The intuition behind  this given that  the income is smaller, his future value is smaller for   a risk averse agent.

 

  • Risky income  positively correlated with the risky asset

 The defining characteristics of this treatment is that the period income is risky and positively  correlated with the risky asset return.  This means  that  when rt rU, Yt is more likely to be equal to yh, and  when  rt  rz , Yt  is more likely to be equal to yl .  The parameters  associated  with  this treatment  are the  following:

T  = 6,  Wo = 10, pu  = 0.5, pd  = 0.5

yh = 4, yl = 0,

 

  • P[Yt = Y 1l rt  ru]  = 0.1, P [Yt  Y 1 l rt  = rd ]  = 0.9
    • P[Yt = Yh l rt  ru]  = 9, P [Yt  Yhl rt  rd ]  = 0.1.

The values of the conditional probabilities of Yt were picked to guarantee that the unconditional probabilities match the values from the treatment without correlation.

 

P [Yt  = y1]  = PuP [Yt  Yl l rt  ru]  +PdP [Yt  Yl l rt  = rd ]  = 0.5         (27)

P [Yt  Yh]  PuP [Yt  Yh l rt  ru]  +PdP [Yt  Y hl rt  = rd ]  = 0.5.       (28)

The intuition behind the the optimal investment  path  is that  now  that the income process is correlated with the return process, the risk associated with the income is implicitly a long position in the risky asset return. Be­ cause of this link, a risk averse subject will be less willing to take risk in this case.

 

  • Risky income negatively correlated with the risky  asset

 In this treatment, the correlation between income and return reverses. When rt ru, Yt is more likely to be equal to 1and when rt r1Yt is more likely to be equal to yh.  The parameters  for this treatment  are the    following:

= 6, Wo = 10, pu  = 0.5, pd  = 0.5

yh = 4, yl  = 0,

  • P[Yt = Y 1l rt  ru]  = 0.9, P [Yt  y 1 l rt  = rd ]  = 0.1
    • P[Yt = Yh l rt  ru]  = 1, P [Yt  yhl rt  rd ]  = 0.9.

The intuition behind the result is that because next period income is negatively correlated with the risky asset return, having income hedges the market risk: when the market goes down, income is high and when it is up the income is down. Under these circumstances, the agents have incentives  to invest more in the risky asset, because, from their  hedge  position  the risky asset is a less risky  bet.

 

Figure 1:

 exper iment 1                • No income group 1

experiment 2                        -+ Fixed income

–. random income

Main question to answer: What is the effect of income?

What is the effect of randomness?

                         What  is the effect  of correlation7

experiment 3                         ·•  osltive correlation

group 2 .,                                                    Would  people  profit  from  the  ability

experiment 4                                • Negative cor relation     Lo hedge their market risk?

 

 

5.2  SUGGESTED  TREATMENTS

 The experimental treatments are summarized in figure 1. For each group, we split the participants in half, each starting the experiment with a different parameterization .

  • Measuring risk preferences

 We plan to measure risk preferences using an experimental task similar to  the one suggested by Holt and Laury  (2002,  2005).  Additionally  we plan  to include several questions that are commonly used in surveys to measure investors  attitudes towards  risk .

  • End of the experiment survey

 In addition to the main experimental treatments described above, we also plan to make a survey at the end of the experiment. The purpose of the questions from the survey is to study the relation between the characteristics of the participants in the experiment  and their  choices.  In particular,  we  are interested  in contrasting  the experiment  results with the following:

  • The socioeconomic  profile:  Age,  gender,  income,  wealth,
  • The risk
  • The level  of  financial literacy.
  • The cognitive reflection profile as described by Frederick (2005) . This questions allow to differentiate between intuitive thinkers (fast thinkers) 24 and reflexive thinkers (slow thinkers), in the way described by Kahne­ man (2011).
  •  
5.2.3  Who will participate  in the experiment?

 There are several populations that will participate in the experiment. The  first one will the group of people that are part of CIRANO’s data base of volunteers to participate in experimental tasks. One limitation of working with this population is that it might not be very representative of the pop­ ulation at large. In particular, this sample has a very large participation of students.

A second group of participants that will take part in the experiment are members  of households  that  participate  in the program  ask Canadians.

The third population that will take part in the experiment is the one composed by finance professionals.

 

 

References

Ameriks,  J.  and  Zeldes,  S. P.  (2004).  How  do household  portfolio  shares vary  with  age. TIAA-CREF  Working Paper. 

Angerer,  X. and Lam,  P.-S.  (2009).  Income risk  and portfolio  choice:  An empirical study. The Journal  of  Finance,  64(2):1037-1055.

Benzoni, L., Collin-Dufresne, P., and Goldstein, R. S. (2007). Portfolio choice over the life-cycle when the stock and labor markets are cointegrated. The Journal of Finance, 62(5):2123-2167.

Bodie, Z., Merton, R. C., and Samuelson, W. F. (1992). Labor supply flexibility  and  portfolio choice in a life cycle model. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 16(3-4) :427-449.

Brocas, I., Carrillo, J. D., Giga, A., and Zapatero, F. (2014). Risk aversion in a dynamic asset allocation experiment.

Calvet, L., Campbell, J. Y., and Sodini, P.  (2007). Down  or  out:  Assessing the welfare costs of household  investment  mistakes.  Journal  of  Political  Economy, 115(5):707-747.

Calvet, L. E. and Sodini, P. (2014). Twin picks: Disentangling the determinants of  risk­ taking  in household  portfolios.   The Journal  of  Finance, 69(2):867-906.

Carbone, E. and Infante, G. (2014). Comparing risk and ambiguity in the life-cycle experiment.

Cardak, B. A. and Wilkins, R. (2009). The determinants of household  risky  asset  hold­  ings: Australian evidence on background risk and other factors. Journal of Banking f3 Finance, 33(5):850-860.

Chiappori, P.-A. and Paiella, M. (2011). Relative risk aversion is constant: Evidence from panel data.  Journal  of  the European  Economic  Association, 9(6):1021-1052.

Cocco, J. F. (2005). Portfolio choice in the presence of housing. Review  of  Financial Studies,   18(2):535-567.

Fagereng, A., Gottlieb, C., and Guiso, L. (2013). Asset market participation and portfolio choice over the life cycle.  CEPR Discussion    Paper. 

Frederick, S. (2005). Cognitive reflection and decision making. The Journal of Economic Perspectives,  19(4):25-42.

Gomes, F. J., Kotlikoff, L. J.,  and  Viceira,  L.  M.  (2008). Optimal  life-cycle  investing with flexible labor supply: A welfare analysis of life-cycle funds. American Economic Review, 98(2):297-303.

Guiso, L. and Sodini, P. (2013). Chapter 21 – household finance: An emerging field. In George M. Constantinides, M. H. and Rene, M. S., editors, Handbook of the Economics of  Finance, volume  Volume 2, Part B, pages  1397-1532.  Elsevier.

Heaton,  J.  and Lucas,  D.  (1997).  Market  frictions,  savings behavior,  and portfolio choice. Macroeconomic  Dynamics, 1(01):76-101.

Heaton, J. and Lucas, D. (2000). Portfolio choice and asset prices: The importance of entrepreneurial  risk.   The  Journal  of  Finance, 55(3):1163-1198.

Holt, C. A. and Laury, S. K. (2002). Risk aversion and incentive effects. The American Economic  Review, 92(5):1644-1655.

Holt, C. A. and Laury, S. K. (2005). Risk aversion and incentive effects: New data without order  effects.   The American  Economic  Review, 95(3):902-904.

Jin, F. (2011). Revisiting the composition puzzles of the household portfolio: New  evi­ dence.  Review  of  Financial  Economics, 20(2):63-73.

Kahneman,  D.  (2011).   Thinking, fast  and  slow. Macmillan.

Kapteyn, A. and Teppa, F. (2014). Subjective measures of risk aversion, fixed costs and portfolio choice.  Journal  of  Economic Psychology.

Klos, A. (2004). The investment horizon and dynamic asset allocation-some experimental evidence.   Economics   Letters, 85(2):167-170.

Koo, H. K. (1999). Consumption and portfolio selection with  labor  income:  A  discrete­  time approach.  Mathematical  Methods  of  Opemtions  Research,  50(2):219-243.

Merton, R. C. (1969). Lifetime portfolio selection under uncertainty: The continuous-time case.  The Review of Economics and Statistics, 51(3):247-257.

Merton, R. C. (1971). Optimum consumption and portfolio rules in a continuous-time model. Journal of Economic Theory, 3(4):373-413.

Mossin,  J.  (1968).   Optimal  multiperiod portfolio policies. The Journal  of  Business, 41(2):215-229.

Peijnenburg,  K. (2014). Life-Cycle  Asset  Allocation with Ambituit y Aversion  and Learning. PhD thesis,  Bocconi University.

Roussanov, N. (2010). Human capital investment and portfolio choice over the life-cycle. Samuelson,  P.  A.  (1963).   Risk  and  uncertainty:   A  fallacy  of  large  numbers.   Scientia, (98) :108-113.

Samuelson,  P. A. (1969).  Lifetime portfolio  selection by dynamic stochastic   programming. The Review  of  Economics  and  Statistics, 51(3):239-246.

Sundali, J. A. and Guerrero, F. (2009). Managing a 401(k) account: An experiment on asset allocation.  Journal of Behavioml Finance,  10(2):108-124.

Veld-Merkoulova, Y. V. (2011). Investment horizon and portfolio choice of private in­ vestors.  International  Review  of  Financial  Analysis,  20(2):68-75.

Viceira, L. M. (2001). Optimal portfolio choice for long-horizon investors with nontradable labor  income.   The Journal  of  Finance, 56(2):433-470.

Wachter,  J. A.  and Yogo,  M.  (2010).  Why  do household  portfolio  shares  rise  in wealth? Review  of  Financial  Studies, 23(11):3929-3965.

Yilmazer, T. and Lich, S. (2013). Portfolio choice and risk attitudes: a household bar­ gaining approach.  Review  of  Economics  of  the Household,  pages 1-23.